Menu
  • Publish Your Research/Review Articles in our High Quality Journal for just USD $99*+Taxes( *T&C Apply)

    Offer Ends On

Research Article

Aspects of Transaction Cost Theory and Principal-Agent Theory in the Three Different Types of Medical Care Centre in Germany

Fabian Renger* and Attila Czirfusz

Corresponding Author: Fabian Renger, Medical Care Centre Dr Renger/Dr Becker, Heidenheim, Germany

Received: February 24, 2022 ;    Revised: March 29, 2022 ;    Accepted: April 01, 2022

Citation:

Copyrights:

Share Your Publication :

Views & Citations

16967

Likes & Shares

0


Global Views

  • Abstract
  • Full Text
  • Images
  • Tables
  • References
  • PDF
  • Supplementary Files

ABSTRACT

Introduction: Since they were approved in 2004, medical care centres have gone on to become an indispensable subsection of the outpatient sector in German.

Object of study: The aims of the legislator have largely been fulfilled, although developments are also occurring that require regulation. The transaction cost approach and the principal-agent theory can be used to analyse the medical care centre.

Objectives: Supporting these medical units is of major importance, both in practical terms and by means of theoretical academic papers.

Methodology: This paper examines the transaction cost approach and the principal-agent theory in connection with the three types of medical care centre.

Results: The transaction cost approach and the principal-agent theory, as subsections of institutional economics, can be applied scientifically to the medical care centre, as medical care centres can largely be considered business-oriented companies.

Conclusions and recommendations for public health action: The interlinking of basic knowledge of business and economics with knowledge of the three types of medical care centre is successful, and the resulting advantages are demonstrated.

Keywords: Medical care centres, Institutional economy, Medical care centre, Transaction cost approach, Principal-agent theory, Connection

INTRODUCTION

Transactions are the basic units of analysis in transaction cost theory [1]. A transaction thus refers to the transfer of so-called rights of disposal to goods and services [2,3]. This transfer generally takes place before the material exchange of goods [4,5] transactions are therefore in principle explicit and implicit (contractual) negotiations regarding goods and services between at least two parties. Transaction cost theory claims that each subject of analysis that can be described explicitly or implicitly as a contractual problem can be analysed on the basis of transaction cost theory [1]. The initiation and execution of contracts causes the parties to incur transaction costs [6,7]. What are transaction costs? Williamson (1985) sees a parallel here to friction in physical systems; transaction costs accordingly function as ‘friction’ in social systems, or in this context, in companies. Transaction costs can occur before or after the conclusion of the contract. Therefore, transaction cost theory differentiates between ex ante and ex post transaction costs [1,8,9]. Ex ante transaction costs are information, negotiation and contractual costs, i.e. costs for contract initiation and agreement. Ex post transaction costs are, in analytical terms, composed of costs for monitoring, implementing and subsequently adjusting the contract conditions, i.e. costs for control and adjustment [5,10]. These costs are therefore considered particularly significant, as it is assumed that a large number of contracts are incomplete, which makes contractual adjustments (and the associated costs) likely (particularly in connection with the assumptions that transaction cost theory makes about behaviour). Transactions are efficient when they are organised by the parties in a way that results in the lowest transaction and production costs - in comparison with other contractual and organisational forms [1,8,9]. Production costs are the costs for the actual production of goods and services. It is assumed that parties select the contractual and organisational alternative that incurs the lowest overall costs. In business economics, this descriptive and explanatory statement (telling us why parties act as they do) is often turned into a normative one (telling us what we should do): ‘You should choose the contractual and organisational alternative that incurs the lowest overall costs.’ The relative advantageousness of a contractual alternative is determined by the sum of the two cost categories [8]. It should be noted that in the descriptions of transaction cost theory given in textbooks and in many of the applications used as examples, the production costs are often kept constant to simplify the analysis and are thus, in principle, excluded from the analysis. Two alternatives are treated as if they differ only in their transaction costs; an (implicit) ceteris paribus state is assumed. Transaction cost theory itself, on the other hand, assumes that transactions executed on the market tend to be associated with lower production costs. Transactions not executed on the market (via an organisation or hierarchy) are suspected by many economists and by transaction costs theorists to be inefficient in most cases [8]. It should, however, be clear that, in reality, alternatives generally have different production costs and that both cost groups should therefore be included in the analysis and taken into account in decision-making processes [9].

OBJECT OF STUDY

Patient / Integrated Care / Types Of Transaction Costs

Aspects of patient care

Implementing patient care that is organised across sectors is one of Germany’s primary health policy objectives. Since the German Statutory Health Insurance Modernisation Act (GMG) came into force on 1 January 2004, it has become more common for integrated care to be arranged in the form of selective contracts. The individual contractual provisions of the integrated care aim to provide incentives for greater innovation and utilise profitability reserves. The identification of deficiencies in healthcare provision and the negotiation and subsequent management of the individual contracts result in transaction costs on the part of both the providers and the health insurance companies, which could overcompensate for the expected profitability reserves. These possible interactions could conflict with the dynamic development processes intended by the legislator [2-16].

Aspects of integrated care

It is claimed that integrated forms of care are able to bring together the resources, healthcare provision, management and organisation of treatment, care, rehabilitation and health promotion [17]. In general, the term ‘integration’ refers to the (re-)creation of a unit. In healthcare, attempts are now being made to organise patient treatment as a unit throughout the medical supply chain [18]. The German Statutory Health Insurance Reform Act, which came into force on 1 January 2000, made it possible for health insurance companies to tackle cross-sector care, on the basis of sections 140a–h of Book V of the German Social Welfare Code (SGB V). For this to be implemented, however, sectoral provisions on budget adjustment were needed. These provisions were agreed between the national associations of the statutory health insurance companies and the National Association of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians [18]. Although integrated care was one of the key aspects of the SHI health reform, because of the budget (adjustment) provisions, it was implemented only in isolated cases until the German Statutory Health Insurance Modernisation Act (GMG) came into force on 1 January 2004 [19]. Figure 1.

Types of transaction costs

Unlike neoclassicism, transaction cost theory accepts that costs are incurred in the course of exchange processes that require information and communications processes and the use of institutional infrastructure in order to be executed [21].

Transaction costs: Transaction costs are incurred for the initiation, maintenance, control and modification of exchange relationships. Accordingly, these costs can be categorised as follows:

  • Initiation costs: Incurred, for example, in the search for suitable transaction partners (market research, analysis of supplier directories, sector analysis, study of performance databases and brochures, rating and review portals, involving consultants for contact initiation etc.).
  • Agreement costs: Costs incurred directly before and during conclusion of the contract. These could include negotiation costs, costs for specifying the range of services and the quality, contract conclusion costs and notary fees.
  • Control costs: Cover the phase after contract conclusion if the concluded contracts are monitored or the agreed services are exchanged (e.g. checking the quality of the delivered goods, monitoring the non-disclosure agreements, acceptance of individual sections, creation of reports on product qualities). In this context, various authors explicitly draw attention to the expenses for the enforcement or implementation of contractual provisions and obligations, listing so-called implementation or enforcement costs separately [22].

  • Adjustment costs: These costs are incurred when contracts need to be changed and/or the transaction relationship needs to be dissolved as the result of new constellations (e.g. revision of contracts, contractual penalties, compensation payments, reports for the enforcement of compensation payments, separation costs). Transaction costs constitute system-inherent costs of exchange in collaboratively organised economic systems that are incurred in both market and hierarchical coordination. If economic entities want to use exchange relationships to improve their situation or overcome shortages, it should for economic reasons be ensured that, in addition to the actual benefits arising from the exchange, the applicable transaction costs are at least compensated. The extent of the perceived shortage, or the need to overcome this shortage, is often not pronounced enough for exchange processes to be worthwhile and for the (transaction) costs required for setting up the necessary institutional infrastructure to be covered by the reduction in shortage (satisfaction of needs). Accordingly, transaction costs can have a ‘prohibitive’ effect on exchange Figure 2.

RESULTS

Transaction Cost Theory

Transaction cost theory differentiates between transaction costs incurred before the contract is concluded (ex ante) and those incurred afterwards (ex post). In the ex ante phase, these mainly comprise information, negotiation and contractual costs The ex post transaction costs comprise development, control and potential adjustment costs of the contract. The ex post phase, which involves examination of the various institutional regulations for safeguarding the contract (e.g. warranty agreements or termination clauses), is given particular importance because of the behavioural assumptions that transaction cost theory is based on. Transaction cost theory is based on three behavioural assumptions: bounded rationality, opportunism and risk neutrality. The first two are described as the main behavioural assumptions. Bounded rationality describes that the transaction partners, despite wanting to behave rationally, are limited in their ability to do so because of incomplete information [1-3,9-11].

Principal-Agent Theory

Fundamentally, the principal-agent theory is a theoretical model that depicts the interaction between two interdependent economic entities with different levels of information. On the one side, there is the principal, who awards a contract, and on the other, the better-informed agent as contractor and provider of the required services. Both parties want to maximise their own benefit, but the unequal distribution of information results in inefficiencies that can lead to market failure [24].

Principal-agent theory model

The principal-agent model attempts to explain the order and service relationship, which is characterised by asymmetrical information, and thus provide the foundation for possible solutions [25].

What is principal-agent theory?

Principal-agent theory is also known by a number of other terms, such as the agency dilemma, the agency problem and the principal-agent problem.

More precisely, principal-agent theory is one of the two subareas of agency theory from economics. The model is also used in the social sciences, sociology and political science, however. Contrary to the positive agency theory subarea, which is more empirical, the second subarea of agency theory, the principal-agent theory, is more practical, constituting a concrete model that attempts to explain economic relationships influenced by information asymmetry. The insight thus gained should enable general statements to be made concerning the optimum design of contracts [24, 25].

Principal

Owner or client, need not perform work themselves, can grant authority to make decisions.

Agent

Person delegated to act, contractor Figures 3 & 4.

If the theory is accepted that MCCs are becoming a powerful and vital component of the supply chain at the interface between the outpatient and inpatient sectors, it follows that MCCs will be brought closer to hospitals. This concerns both the geographical situation and the provision of services. In the target model, it is realistic for MCC and hospital to work together closely to jointly provide care for patients in need of treatment. In this mode, one MCC works with one hospital exclusively and over the long term. The close connection then enables the provision of services to be integrated to form a joint process [2,3,6,7,24,27]. MCC and hospital are located on the same premises, or adjoining premises, and they share healthcare resources and tasks. The MCC provides outpatient services, while the hospital focuses on inpatient services. This means that services delivered and billed by the hospital on an outpatient basis are also transferred to the MCC, which provides these services in processes and structures optimised for outpatient cases. The hospital is thus able to keep resources designed and optimised for inpatient care free from outpatient cases, which pose a hindrance to hospital workflows. For legal, organisational or economic reasons, complete transfer of outpatient services from the hospital to the MCC are likely to be limited, so gradual manifestation of the target model is to be expected, with some remnants remaining in the inpatient structure [2,3,6,7,24,27]. To keep outpatient cases consistently within the outpatient structure, in this model all cases are registered and admitted in the MCC, which becomes the central initial point of contact for MCC and hospital. The workflows and the personnel for patient management are thus pooled and can be optimised for efficiency and professionalism. Whether emergency admission should continue to be performed in the hospital so that serious cases can be referred directly for treatment and an inpatient stay depends on the organisational capabilities of the medical personnel. In any case, emergency admission should take an interdisciplinary approach and be staffed by specialists so that emergencies as well as outpatient and elective inpatient cases can legitimately enter a uniform diagnostic and triage procedure in accordance with standardised patient pathways. Diagnostics is located centrally, in particular for large-scale equipment, so that it can be used efficiently for outpatient and inpatient cases equally, and also for laboratory or pathology where they are not outsourced. In addition, it could be beneficial to set up an admissions and short-stay station that can be used for observing day surgery cases while also keeping the stations free from potential outpatient cases, or inpatient cases with no clear responsible specialist department, during a prolonged diagnostic and triage process (prevention of primary or secondary misallocation) [2,3,6,7,24,27]. Optionally, the target model can be supplemented with a gate principle that requires defined conditions to be met for the patient to be transferred to the next step in the patient pathway. The basic model was originally developed for innovation and development processes and has since been adapted in various company models. In the process workflow shown (see infographic above), the gate model can ensure at the first gate that diagnostics is only begun once patient admission has been fully completed, an admission DRG has been documented and, in relevant cases, a specialist has been consulted. This means that the extent and the process of diagnostics can be reduced to the minimum necessary, in accordance with a standard operating procedure (SOP). At the second gate, the necessity of inpatient treatment can be decided on and treatment can be initiated on the basis of structured and complete information, with the involvement of specified doctors or interdisciplinary teams. In unclear cases, the admissions and short-stay station can be accessed as needed. The patient can leave this station at the third gate if either outpatient treatment has been or will be performed, or clear allocation to a specialist department is possible on the basis of the work DRG. The gate principle can thus largely reduce the uncertainty of action that may arise from the close connection of outpatient and inpatient care [2,3,6,7,24,27].

CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS FOR PUBLIC HEALTH ACTION

Understanding the meaning behind the transaction cost approach and the principal-agent theory requires a fundamental analysis and depiction of these two scientific areas. This is the only way to successfully bridge the function of these approaches for the MCC. The transaction cost approach addresses all costs incurred from the business and economic perspective. Applied to the MCC, these are the costs from the initiation or from a doctor’s appointment to the conclusion of the treatment. In the principal-agent theory, the influencing factors of relationships are investigated, and in the context of this article, the factors of the doctor-patient contact. Advantages for public health are created by the applicability and provision of knowledge from a global perspective and by optimisation possibilities in specific cases, such as the doctor-patient contact in an individual appointment.

There are three different types of MCC, and they have different business characteristics. MCCs are institutions and can be depicted within the framework of institutional economics. MCCs are a form of service provider in healthcare, initiated by the legislator.

REFERENCES

  1. Williamson OE (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, Free Press; Reprint Edition, New York.
  2. Steinecker M, Czirfuszovà M, Mrázová M (2019) Diluted property rights and analysis of business administration categories in the three types of Medical Care Centres in Germany, in: Zdravotníctví a sociální práce 14(1): 1-9.
  3. Steinecker M, Czirfuszová M (2021) Examining the three types of medical care centers in relation to transaction cost theory. Int J Health 16(2): 64-71.
  4. Picot A, Dietl H (1990) Transaktionskostentheorie, in: Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium. LMU 19: 178-184.
  5. Picot A (1982) Transaktionskostenansatz in der Organisationstheorie: Stand der Diskussion und Aussagewert, in: Die Betriebswirtschaft LMU 42(2): 267-284.
  6. Renger F, Czirfusz A (2017) Die drei verschiedenen Typen von Medizinischen Versorgungszentren unter institutionstheoretischen Gesichtspunkten. Eine typologische Public-Health-Betrachtung. Hamburg: Verlag Dr. Kovač, pp: 105.
  7. Renger F, Czirfusz, A (2019) Modellbildung bei den drei Typen von Medizinischen Versorgungszentren unter Gesichtspunkten der Property Rights-Theorie. Eineinstitutionstheoretische Betrachtung. Hamburg: Verlag Dr. Kovac pp: 114.
  8. Hartweg HR (2007) Ein evolutions- und transaktionskostentheoretischer Beitrag zu den Entwicklungspotenzialen der integrierten Versorgung in der Gesetzlichen Krankenversicherung, in: Zeitschrift für öffentliche und gemeinwirtschaftliche Unternehmen: ZögU 30(3): 317-331.
  9. Ebers M, Gotsch W (1995) Institutionenökonomische Theorien der Organisation, in: Kieser, A. (Ed.): Organisationstheorien, 2., rev. ed.
  10. Renger F, Steinecker M, Renger A, Czirfusz A (2019) Overview about medical care centres in Germany under institutional economics aspects. In: Zdravotníctví a sociální práce. 14(3): 125-128.
  11. Renger F (2009) Aspekte der Personalauswahl in Medizinischen Versorgungszentren unter besonderer Berücksichtigung des Interventionsmodells von Kieser. GRIN: pp. 1-102.
  12. Renger F (2012a) Typisierung des Medizinischen Versorgungszentrums von Freiberuflern als Beitrag zur Unternehmensführung. Norderstedt Germany: Grin Verlag pp: 1-9.
  13. Renger F (2012b) Unternehmensführungsgesichtspunkte des Medizinischen Versorgungszentrums, insbesondere der Beschaffung, Finanzierung / Investition und des Qualitätsmanagements. Norderstedt Germany: Grin Verlag pp: 1-10.
  14. Renger F (2012c) Führungskonzepte in Medizinischen Versorgungszentren mit besonderer Betrachtung von Erlösfaktoren. Norderstedt Germany: Grin Verlag pp: 1-10.
  15. Renger F, Czirfusz A (2017) Praktische Ratschläge für die Gründung eines Medizinischen Versorgungszentrums (MVZs) mit integrierter Public-Health-Perspektive. Grin Verlag pp: 75.
  16. Renger F, Czirfusz A (2021) Marketing, Public Relations and Aspects of Investment in the Medical Care Centre in Germany. J Nurs Mid Res 1(1): 1-8.
  17. Graf OM (2006) Jahrbuch Oskar der Maria Graf-Gesellschaft by Dittmann U, Dollinger H (Eds.), pp: 122.
  18. Mühlbacher A, Lubs S, Röhrig N, Schultz A, Zimmermann I, et al. (2006) Status Quo der Integrierten Versorgung in Deutschland: eine empirische Analyse. (ZiGprint, 2006-03). Berlin: Zentrum für innovative Gesundheitstechnologie an der Technischen Universität Berlin. Available online at: https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168- ssoar-379349
  19. Drumm S, Achenbach A (2005) Integrierte Versorgung erfolgreich gestalten mit Klinischen Pfaden - Taschenbuch. Ecomed. pp: 176.
  20. Heyd R, Beyer M (2013) Die Transaktionskostentheorie in der Finanzwirtschaft, Erich Schmidt Verlag, 1st edn.
  21. Schneider D (2016) (Nach-) Denkseiten: Transaktionskostentheorie: Organisationsformen zwischen “Markt” und „Hierarchie“ und ihre Evolution - am Ende grüßt die Neoklassik, taken in slightly modified form from: Schneider, D. (2016): Grundlagen der Betriebswirtschaftslehre, Kompaktes Basiswissen, 2., extended edition, Norderstedt, pp: 115-128.
  22. Kräkel M (1999) Ökonomische Analyse der betrieblichen Karrierepolitik. 2., überarbeitete Auflage, International vergleichende Schriften zur Personalökonomie und Arbeitspolitik, Rainer Hampp Verlag, München und Mering pp: 8.
  23. Wiegandt P (2018) Arbeitspapier Nr. 14 der Leibniz-Fachhochschule Hannover Integrierte Versorgung Untersuchung der Entscheidungsdeterminanten gesetzlicher Krankenkassen zum Abschluss integrierter Versorgungsverträge.
  24. N.a. (2021) Integrierte Versorgung. Available online at: https://www.leibniz-fh.de/content/uploads/2019/09/Arbeitspapier_14_Integrierte_Versorgung_NEU.pdf
  25. N.a. (2021) principal-agent theory. Available online at: https://www.bwl-lexikon.de/wiki/prinzipal-agent-theorie/
  26. N.a. (2021) principal-agent theory. Availble online at: https://www.google.de/search?q=Prinzipa-Agent-Theorie
  27. N.a. (2021) n.t. Availble online at: https://www.polavis.de/blog/mvz-medizinisches-versorgungszentrum-in-10-jahren
  28. Kalyan KS, Sangeetha S (2020) Target Concept Guided Medical Concept Normalization in Noisy User-Generated Texts, In: Proceedings of Deep Learning Inside Out (DeeLIO): The First Workshop on Knowledge Extraction and Integration for Deep Learning Architectures, pp: 4-73.Accessed on: March 24, 2022. Available online at: https://aclanthology.org/2020.deelio-1.8.pdf

    No Files Found